I Get By With Alittle Help From My Friends....
Would you like to react to this message? Create an account in a few clicks or log in to continue.
I Get By With Alittle Help From My Friends....

Dinar Outcast


You are not connected. Please login or register

The international monetary system is in need of real reform

Go down  Message [Page 1 of 1]

Guest


Guest

Saturday August 8, 2009

The international monetary system is in need of real reform

WHAT ARE WE TO DO
BY TAN SRI LIN SEE YAN

ONCE in a while, we have good reason to feel unhappy with the US dollar. Not only did the United States bring down the global economy, whatever wealth there was left in the dollar was subject to significant diminution.

After peaking in 2002, the trade-weighted US dollar had depreciated ever since. Sure, the dollar has since been given a temporary lift on its safe haven status.

As things stand today, it’s just a matter of time before the dollar, as it begins to further weaken, to once again take its toll.

So, we are all caught in a strange quagmire. Strange because ever since I was little, the dollar – known in Cantonese as mei-kum or American gold – is now anything but a quagmire, on account of feeling caught in a trap: in good times, you feel safe holding-on to mei-kum. When things turn sour, you can’t (as a group) get out of the dollar’s assets fast enough, without “cutting your nose to spite your face.” How did we get here? Some history will be helpful.

US dollar as an anchor and reserve

After World War II (WWII), the US financial system was the only one kept intact.

There was even runaway inflation, widespread currency restrictions, rationing and price control, etc. in Europe, Japan and most other countries.

The American economy was the strongest then and the dollar was very much in demand. For the US, winning the war didn’t hurt.

And so, under the Bretton Woods agreement of 1945, every nation pegged to the dollar. But the dollar was not required to have a formal exchange rate peg – except for the residual tie to gold. Hence, mei-kum.

Soon, one thing led to another and the dollar became a natural monopoly mainly because of economies of scale. The more nations that dealt in the US dollar, the cheaper and more convenient it was to trade in that currency.

Before you know it, the dollar became the text-book anchor and reserve currency (along side the pound sterling, which even before WWII was already a reserve currency, but was devastated by war). To do this well, the US price level has to be kept stable and remain so.

To complement this role, the dollar met what has come to be known as Kenen’s rule of international money: a reserve currency must have the ability to facilitate as a medium of exchange, a store of value, a unit of account, and a standard of deferred payment for international transactions (for example, bonds). The US dollar and the dollar exchange standard have been so from 1945 into the new millennium.

The Bretton Woods system

The dollar standard is supposed to work within the Bretton Woods-designed international monetary system (IMS), which is based on four main principles: right of each nation to manage internal demand to meet the objective of growth with price stability; exchange rate convertibility in the face of free movement of goods, services and capital as a means to achieve efficient use of resources; international trade to be conducted on an adjustable-peg exchange rate regime with provision for material changes in the event of structural imbalances; and countries hold own-reserves but given a line-of-credit by the International Monetary Fund (IMF).

However, the system began to unravel in the late 1960s. The special drawing right (SDR) was created by the IMF in 1969 as a new international reserve asset to supplement existing reserves. Nixon closed the “gold window” in 1971. By 1973, the US dollar parities were abandoned and currencies moved to non-par floating.

High and variable inflation in the 1970s-1980s eroded the dollar’s usefulness as anchor. The euros only came into its own in late 1990s.

Despite the changes and more flexibility in exchange rate regimes, the overall basic structure of the IMS had remained essentially the same.

It still faced three underlying difficulties: no reliable mechanism to correct international payments imbalances; it is subject to destabilising speculative bouts; and no orderly arrangement to generate in a predictable way, new reserves to meet demands of a growing world economy.

Hence, you now see the mess we are in today. Clearly, the IMS is in need of real reform.

Payments surpluses good or bad?

A nation with a payments deficit means it is importing (spending) more than it exports (earns). It settles this by losing reserves or borrows to cover it (for example, living off its savings or on credit). Often, it has to deflate, slow-down, or devalue (or some combination), which brings about a dilemma in the form of conflict of policy objectives.

In other words, any adjustment comes at a cost. But one thing is certain, continuing deficits are not sustainable (for example, the United States). Similarly, a payments surplus nation exports too much (saves). To adjust, it has to inflate, push-growth or revalue – each of which (or a combination thereof) also comes at a cost.

Like persistent deficits, continuing surpluses are also not sustainable (for example, Japan and China). For the world system to get back into balance, both surplus and deficit countries have to adjust – that is, the surplus nation has to expand and the deficit nation, contract.

But, in practice – unlike the gold standard – the Bretton Woods system has no reliable mechanism to make both of them adjust. And, both parties find adjustment just too costly. Hence, this often precipitates in a crisis which forces adjustment, at a time that is usually sub-optimal.

To most, deficits are bad. Why? After all, the idea of trade is to obtain goods and services from abroad that costs less than they can be produced at home.

Imports are the fruits of foreign trade. So, an excess of imports has to be good – for the deficit nation most certainly. But that’s just part of the story because the excess of imports over exports has to be paid for, resulting in having less reserves or using up borrowing power – either may not be the most comfortable.

And adjustments can be costly in economic terms, whether in slowing down the economy or having to devalue currency. Similarly, surpluses may sound good but are actually not. It can be inflationary and represent an inefficient use of resources. For the surplus country, the saving reflects the mere hoarding of resources, which otherwise could be invested to enhance future output and welfare.

Adjustments back to equilibrium here can be just as costly in terms of having to revalue currency or stimulate spending.

2The international monetary system is in need of real reform Empty part 2 Sat Aug 08, 2009 12:11 pm

Guest


Guest

US dollar reserves

The world is driven into the dollar trap. Like it or not, countries especially in Asia, have been accumulating reserves. As at end of the first quarter of 2009, these reserves totalled US$6.5 trillion (65% is held in US dollars, 26% in euros, 4% in pound sterling and 3% in yen), close to one-half of the United States gross domestic product (GDP).

Indeed, up to three-quarters of all reserves are in the hands of emerging nations. China alone holds two-thirds of the global stash, or US$2.2 trillion (more than one-half of its own GDP).

Of these, some 35% remains invested in US Treasuries.

Realistically, Asia especially China, is “hooked” on the dollar. It is worth noting that about 70% of world trade is invoiced in dollars. Is there room to diversity into euros or SDRs?

The euro

The book, The Euro at Ten: The Next Global Currency?, made an interesting observation; that despite the recent US induced currency meltdown and global recession, the consequent “flight to safety of world savings was to US Treasuries, and not noticeably to the euro.”

There are four reasons for this: European banking and capital markets are not as sophisticated and more fragmented; the Eurozone lacks correct rules and tools of governance; the euro has yet to become an effective anchor of regional stability; and the euro appears likely to become more and more a regional currency.

Sure, the euro is now a credible currency. But the commitment of Eurozone governments to run up large payments deficits (in order to issue more euros) is questionable. Besides, the euro appears over-valued today.

Special drawing rights

For Paul Krugman, special drawing rights (SDRs) “aren’t real money”. They are units of account at the IMF which value is set by a basket of dollars, euros, yen and pound sterling (44% weight assigned to the dollar).

In practice, it is possible to buy IMF bonds that are linked to the SDR to diversify away from the dollar. Brazil, Russia and China have indicated their interest to invest in such SDR bonds.

However, these bonds can only be traded among central banks, in which case, a nation will be better-off by directly raising its holdings of euro, pound sterling and yen to reflect their SDR weighting.

However, any move to do so in a significant way could prove counterproductive. I am sure new and innovative ways will be designed to enhance the stature and role of the SDR.

But I am not optimistic about its future at this time, despite strong support from China and Russia in particular. SDRs today account for less than 1% of world reserves. More work needs to be done.

New realities for China

China is a big part of this dollar trap. It holds one-third of world reserves; two-thirds of its holdings are in US dollar assets in the face of world reserves that are also two-thirds invested in US dollar assets.

By 2010, China is expected to overtake Japan as the world’s second largest economy. By end 2009, China looks certain to overtake Germany as the world’s second largest trading nation.

Yet, China cannot have unrealistic expectations. After all, the dollar did not replace the pound sterling for 50 years after the US economy had overtaken Britain.

Today, the US GDP is three times as big as China, and US total trade is still way larger. Moreover, more than 70% of world trade is conducted in the dollar. So China has some way to go. Be that as it may, China has emerged in a changed world since end 2007.

The phenomenon of prolonged, persistent payments surpluses has to be a thing of the past. What is now urgently needed is a reliable international mechanism to correct fundamental imbalances in both deficit and surplus nations.

I can’t see a system as being stable in which only Asia and Germany save. Of course, Americans have already begun to save too.

Similarly, stability won’t come easy where mere exchange rate revaluation on the part of those with surpluses can – as if by a magic stroke of the pen – resolve the spent-thrift ways of those with persistent deficits.

Recent experience suggests the rules of the game need to be changed. Indeed, new economic realities are already changing the costs and benefits of being a reserve currency.

3The international monetary system is in need of real reform Empty part 3 Sat Aug 08, 2009 12:12 pm

Guest


Guest

China’s global role

As I see it, China will have to assume new responsibilities to help resolve the dollar trap. To begin with, it will need to internationalise the renminbi (RMB).

This will help facilitate its use as a reserve currency. However, it must meet Kenen’s rule.

Also, it means moving – over time – towards capital account convertibility, sooner rather than later. Recent initiatives to invoice and settle trade in RMB between Hong Kong and the five big trading cities (including Shanghai and Guangzhou), will naturally expand.

Similarly, the series of currency swap arrangements (totalling US$650mil) with Asean, South Korea, Argentina and Brazil form part of the same process.

The intention is to support and widen the settlement of more and more inter-and intra-Asian trade in RMB and other local currencies.

These are necessary first steps. To succeed, complementary initiatives to open-up, broaden and deepen the banking and capital markets of China will be required.

I believe there is merit in China’s proposal for a super-sovereign reserve currency based on IMF’s SDR – as a move away from reliance on currency of a single sovereign nation, no matter how strong.

Support by India and Russia of an IMF issued SDR-based fund is promising. Realistically, it is extremely unlikely that the dollar will be replaced as a reserve currency anytime soon.

Nevertheless, the world needs to move innovatively and act boldly. In the short-run, an expanded SDR will be needed, evolving step-by-step into a real-time trading and settlement currency in world markets. Presumably, the RMB will be included at some time in the SDR basket.

In the final analysis, what is called for is a workable package deal – a realistic attempt at comprehensive reform of the entire IMS.

Present piecemeal efforts won’t do. A really new (not just improved) Bretton Woods has to emerge. I don’t see how the dollar trap can be satisfactorily resolved otherwise. This has to be a long-term commitment. To do otherwise is foolhardy, but the US won’t like it.

·Former banker, Dr Lin is a Harvard educated economist and a British chartered scientist who now spends time promoting the public interest. Feedback is most welcome. Please email to starbizweek@thestar.com.my

Sponsored content



Back to top  Message [Page 1 of 1]

Permissions in this forum:
You cannot reply to topics in this forum